Skip to content
Deacon Keith Fournier Hi readers, it seems you use Catholic Online a lot; that's great! It's a little awkward to ask, but we need your help. If you have already donated, we sincerely thank you. We're not salespeople, but we depend on donations averaging $14.76 and fewer than 1% of readers give. If you donate just $5.00, the price of your coffee, Catholic Online School could keep thriving. Thank you. Help Now >

'Justice, Aid and Poverty' - Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences

Free World Class Education
FREE Catholic Classes

VATICAN CITY, MAY 27, 2007 (Zenit) - Here is the contribution from Edmond Malinvaud to the round table "International Justice and Aid" in the 13th plenary session of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences. The session was held from April 27 - May 1.

* * *

Justice, aid and poverty: a short survey of the literature
E. Malinvaud[1]

In this session, dedicated to "Charity and justice in the relations among peoples and nations," we accept the idea that international justice calls for an increase in aid to the poorest countries. This round table is meant to study how the increase should be patterned so as to implement as well as possible a just reduction in poverty. That is a wide-ranging matter to the clarification of which a short survey of the literature may contribute, even though it will leave aside how the increase in aid will be financed, an issue that other members of the round table will better tackle than I could do.

The first two parts of this paper will essentially consider a literature that existed before the millennium goals were chosen. Their title will respectively be: "What Would International Justice Require?" "Poverty, Aid and Economic Growth." The literature of the last decade, which was particularly rich, will be the subject of the last part.

We ask you, humbly: don't scroll away.

Hi readers, it seems you use Catholic Online a lot; that's great! It's a little awkward to ask, but we need your help. If you have already donated, we sincerely thank you. We're not salespeople, but we depend on donations averaging $14.76 and fewer than 1% of readers give. If you donate just $5.00, the price of your coffee, Catholic Online School could keep thriving. Thank you.

Help Now >

What would international justice require?

Philosophy often closely examined what justice should be. But our concern in this round table is to reach operative proposals. Attempting to survey fundamental debates between philosophers would be misplaced.[2] We shall rather consider, directly and in turn, justice according to the humanist philosopher Paul Ricoeur, the application of justice in law, and the application of justice in international relations.

Justice according to Paul Ricoeur[3]

This philosopher takes a strong position against the idea that principles of justice could be derived from rational reasoning only. He points instead to the relevance of a teleological perspective inspired by the sense of justice rooted in the mind of men and women who yearn for meaningful lives, with and for others within just institutions.

What matters is first to appeal to practical wisdom in judging each context in itself. It is also the emergence of an ethic in the process by which argumentations and convictions are exchanged between persons, are progressively improved, up to the point where considered convictions might have a fair degree of universality. Ricoeur then concludes: "The skill of conversation in which the ethics of argumentation is put to the test of the conflict of convictions makes up one of the faces of practical wisdom."

Social scientists have a natural role to play in Ricoeur scheme. They seldom claim to dictate what institutions and social policies ought to be. Their role is rather to reflect on social realities and to present evidence showing what the positive or negative effects of institutions and policies are likely to be. The argumentations in which they are involved, in relation with the demands addressed to them, help to the formation of considered convictions in the citizenry.

Application of justice in law

All social scientists may now benefit from occasionally referring to the three volumes of the Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law (Macmillan, 1998, London). These volumes are relevant in particular for the discussion in our round table, because they lead readers to reflect on the application of justice.

In entry "justice," A. de Jasay begins with: "The concept of justice informs our sense of justice." The first part is entitled "findings and judgments," the second "donstituent principles" with the subheadings "responsibility," "presumption," "convention." We perceive continuity with the thinking of Ricoeur and a distance from the two principles stated by Rawls (1971).

The dictionary well exhibits three important distinctions in the constituting of law: (i) common law and written law; (ii) legal justice and social justice; (iii) render unto each "his own" or "according to his needs." I shall say no more about the first distinction. But the second leads us to refer to the entry "social justice" where we find the two relevant definitions. For legal justice: "exercise of impartiality in enforcing the system of rights and duties by which a basic level of order in society is achieved"; for social justice: "ensuring that each individual is given his due, not in terms of a claim to just conduct on the part of others, but as an assigned share of society wealth." This induces us to refer to entry "equity," but it turns out that the entry is focused on the "jurisdiction of equity," which I understand to be a historical distinctive feature of some English courts.

There is no doubt in my mind that the drive for fighting against poverty belongs to social justice applied to those most suffering from destitution. But the above third distinction brings into conflict two sensitivities which clearly appear in philosophical literature. The second one goes back to Roman law and to the principle Suum cuique heading the fourth part of the entry "justice." The principle in question literally translates from Latin as: "to each his own."

It states the existence of a private property right, understood as one form of personal liberty. Now, various authors maintain that the latter has prime importance. Rawls (1971) in particular gave primacy to his first principle of justice requiring "the most extensive basic liberties." The second principle, presented as subsidiary, states that justice must also ensure "the most restricted social and economic inequalities." Among those who strongly argued for the primacy of liberty I may mention the philosopher Robert Nozick and the Nobel prize economist Friedrick Hayek.

I may also recall to the mind of academicians that, in our second plenary session, labor and employment law was examined by the contribution of Thomas Kohler, who compared the German model, as a continental European prototype, to the U.S. model. The German law was meant to protect the weaker party to the employment contract. The American law took its inspiration from liberal anthropology. So, concerning collective bargaining, the legal schemes entail minimal state intervention in the ordering of relationship because they rely on market mechanisms to shape the results.

Application of justice in international relations

International justice appears as a major theme in the program of this session. I am therefore dedicating to it just a short section, which might however overlap other written texts submitted to this session.

Over much of the 20th century, there has been an important widening and deepening in the scope of the international legal order. However, it would be hard to argue that justice was the predominant concern.[4]

Historically, the main mode to put order was through bilateral treaties: Equally sovereign states pursuing their respective national interest would bargain and in principle come to some form of transaction. But actually the interest of the strong was often imposed to the weak. Appearance in the 20th century of multilateral agreements rooted, in each case, on a certain world view somewhat mitigated the risk of imbalance. But major states of North America and Europe still frequently imposed their rule on lesser states, leaving the latter with little or no margin of negotiation.

The development of international organizations led to search for an orderly international community, although through many setbacks. More or less constraining international norms progressively replaced some of the national norms. This was by and large beneficial. But we could not accept without reservation today the claim that international normality would meet the requirement of justice.

One often hears about a "global governance." But it is undertaken only in a tentative incomplete way, and it has to put up with a high degree of national disharmonies. Elements of a civil society spread beyond national borders, but they poorly interact with national governments and international organizations. Behind such lacks of mutual adaptability transpires the frequent disagreement between value systems, each one claiming universality.

Who, such being the case, can define the content of international justice?

3. Poverty, aid and economic growth

2.1. What is poverty of the human person? How can it be measured?

Introducing his article on the subject A. Atkinson (1987) writes: "Concern for poverty has been expressed over the centuries, even if its priority on the agenda for political action has not always been high. Its different meanings and manifestations have been the subject of study by historians, sociologists and economists. Its causes have been identified in a wide variety of sources, ranging from deficiencies in the administration of income support to the injustice of the economic and social system. The relief, or abolition, of poverty has been sought in the reform of social security, in intervention in the labor market, and in major changes in the form of economic organization."

In the context of this round table, attention is naturally confined to countries of the Third World where poverty is acute and seems to be more easily identified than in developed countries, in which such notions as "conditions of living" permit wide ranges of interpretations.[5]

However we must keep in mind the distinction made by Atkinson between a minimum level of consumption or income, a kind of subsistence level, and a right to have at least a given share of the total amount of resources available in the society. This second concept refers to a statistical distribution of the levels of consumption or income in that society. We then say the first measure is "absolute" and the second is "relative."

Referring to the proportion of people living below one 1990 dollar a day, the particular millennium goal which most concerns us here has chosen an absolute measure of poverty, whereas poverty indicators quoted for developed countries were often chosen as relative. Let us still note at this point that, in section 3.1, other millennium goals will be mentioned, which may also enter into the numerical description of poverty.

Deacon Keith Fournier Hi readers, it seems you use Catholic Online a lot; that's great! It's a little awkward to ask, but we need your help. If you have already donated, we sincerely thank you. We're not salespeople, but we depend on donations averaging $14.76 and fewer than 1% of readers give. If you donate just $5.00, the price of your coffee, Catholic Online School could keep thriving. Thank you. Help Now >

2.2. Why should we talk about growth?

There are two reasons for doing so: facts and history of ideas. On the one hand, economic growth usually goes hand in hand with the gradual reduction in poverty. Since growth factors have been much studied in economics, what is known about them in such or such country already, although imperfectly, gives information about poverty.

On the other hand, a large literature was published since the end of the 50s dealing with the effects of foreign aid on the growth of little developed countries. This literature fostered a long debate and so makes up a useful background for appraising the relevance of recent contributions.

It had emerged at the very time when was appearing an increasing disillusion in relation to the slowness of the take-off in some assisted countries, the absence of any take-off in others, and what was perceived about the utilization of aids. A parallel was drawn with the luxurious life of some ruling leaders, with the spread of corruption along the channels which distributed aids without caring about their best use. Or still allocation of aids turned out to benefit only an elite or to go into poorly worked-out projects, the materialization of which could even reveal to be useless in practice.

Some economists explained that aid had pernicious effects because it could prevent the natural development of entrepreneurship and could have the harmful effect of leading to overvaluation of the currency, thus handicapping exporters of home products. What was happening in the Netherlands since the tapping of natural gas reserves (the "Dutch disease") was presented as illustrative.

Of course, such pessimistic diagnoses were not unanimously accepted. They were not accepted for instance by H. Chenery and A. Strout (1966) who, in their modeling of aid effects, believed to be building on a solid theoretical basis. The latter had indeed been widely distributed by well reputed development economists like Arthur Lewis (1954).

However neither factual data nor analytical principles to process them were still well established, whereas they would progressively emerge later with time. In fact we shall have occasions to see that such data and principles do not remove all difficulties. Nevertheless a methodology would be worked out for testing the various forms of aid.

We must also recognize that something still stands today to be remembered out of the early criticism. W. Easterly (2003) in his pages 36 to 38 quotes aberrations to which some institutions in charge of distributing international aid still recently succumbed.

2.3. Impact of aid on growth through investment

Published in 1960 a book by W. Rostow was for a time very popular among economists. According to the author economic development began with a period of take-off, following stagnation, when society began to build up capital. Once under way growth would go on almost automatically. Many then accepted the thesis that foreign aid would serve as a release mechanism.

In their model, Chenery and Stout accepted the idea, moreover assuming that aid would fully go to investment. Domestic saving would be proportional to the growth rate. International trade would sooner or later generate a surplus, which would progressively substitute for aid. Notwithstanding the restrictive character of the assumptions so made, the model proposed a reasonable framework for thoughts. It could even lend itself to computations, at the time when economic planning was fashionable and investment was made mainly of industrial equipments and transport infrastructures.

2.4. A larger vision of growth factors

During the three following decades, the concept of factors of growth was enlarged in two successive stages. First, great importance was recognized to "human capital," hence to education and health. The goal was no longer only to finance imports, but also to train teachers and doctors.

There would be little reason to stress this point, except for a blame often addressed to the structural adjustment programs imposed by IMF or the World Bank: Particularly in the poorest countries, these programs often turned out to mean drastic cuts in the budgets allocated to education and public health. There may be a lesson for us to draw today: We should not neglect to think about humanitarian aid, which also directly concerns human capital.

Starting in the decade of the 1980s a number of economists took the habit to include, among possible growth factors of a country, its institutions, which may either stimulate or hinder growth. I need not dwell on the fact that, since that time, market economies were recognized as definitely more favorable to growth than tightly controlled economies. On the other hand, within the category of market economies, performances widely differ and depend on the forms of regulations ruling the various markets, as well as on the quality of the governance applied by private and public agents.

Claiming to present all the economic literature dealing with the various aspects quickly alluded to above would be misplaced in this commentary. It will be better to now draw attention to what was published recently.

Light Your Free Payer Candle for a departed loved one

What is Palm Sunday?

Live on March 20, 2024 @ 10am PDT

3. Literature of the last decade

Dedicated to our subject, this literature is rich. It takes advantage of a quickly increasing collection of data in poor countries, of the progress of methods for data analysis and of the multiplicity of research projects, which could be led with a good level of objectivity. Nevertheless debates did not vanish, as applied econometrics faced difficulties, the diagnosis of which remains somewhat uncertain.

Section 3.1 will outline the recent trends in absolute poverty compared with the millennium goals. Section 3.2 will explain how enrichment of data bases and deepening of the econometric methodology to analyze them opened new fields for research. Section 3.3 will examine how income redistribution may contribute to the reduction in poverty. Section 3.4 will single out a category made of those aids which may be assumed to stimulate growth in the short run. Section 3.5 will bring to the fore the fundamental difficulty of the evaluation of long run effects of aid policies. Section 3.6 will deal with the agenda for reducing poverty.

3.1. Trends in absolute poverty compared with the main Millennium goal

For good reason, T. Besley and B. Burgess (2003) wrote: "Obtaining reliable measures of poverty requires household surveys about the distribution of income or consumption that are comparable across countries" (p. 4).

They pointed out that, over the last twenty years, the World Bank Research Department conducted a systematic operation with that purpose, covering in 2000 about 88 countries which, out of a total of 158 low and middle-income countries, represented about 89% of the total population of the developing world. That data source led to evaluate at 29% in 1990 and 24% in 1998 the proportion of people who, in those countries, were living with a purchasing power below one dollar a day (at a constant real parity of the dollar).

These two proportions much varied from one region of the Third World to another. They amounted to 48% and 46% for sub-Saharan Africa, to 44% and 40% for South Asia, as against, for instance, 17% and 16% for Latin America, 15% and 10% for East Asia and Pacific (excluding China).

It so appeared that the last one of the large regions here quoted was on the right track to meet the millennium goal of cutting in half between 1990 and 2015 the proportion of those living below one dollar a day. On the other hand, a strong acceleration after the period 1990-98 was required for the same goal to be met by sub-Saharan Africa or Latin America. Urgency of such an acceleration is one of the reasons which motivated organizers of this session, notably for this round table.

Moreover we should not limit our discussion to just one of the millennium goals. Hence, I must quote three other neighboring goals. Concerning education: achieving by 2015 universal primary education. Concerning health: from 1990 to 2015 reducing by half the proportion of people without access to safe drinking water, by two-third under-age-five mortality, by three-quarters maternal mortality; also reversing the spread of the HIV/AIDS. For environment: ensuring environmental sustainability.

3.2. Enrichment of data and analytical methods

In order to reply to those economists who had stood as detractors of foreign aid (see 2.2 above), other economists more recently chose an opposite stand, while recognizing some part of truth in the formers arguments. They claimed and sometimes proved that the strength of these arguments had been overstated. International aid would have sustained poverty reduction and growth in some countries and have avoided worse outcomes in others. Some supporters also believe that many failings of aid have more to do with donors than recipients, especially since much aid is given to political allies rather than to sustain development.

It is not surprising that, after 50 years of experience, it became possible to now issue a more qualified assessment and to more meticulously analyze the impact of aid, depending on the various motivations and contexts surrounding it. Indeed, the means now at the disposal of research on aid are much more extensive and appropriate than those available in older days.

In the first place, factual information was much enriched. Today research has access to large data banks, the content of which has admittedly a variable reliability from one country to another, but a reliability that overall keeps improving.

Various typologies were set up, for instance about the quality of public, or even private, governance in aid receiving countries. This is how G. Burnside and D. Dollar (2000) were led to the conclusion that foreign aid had a positive impact in those developing countries which were well managed, with sound fiscal, monetary and trade policies, but that aid had no significant impact in countries applying loose policies (the conclusion was however disputed subsequently, as we shall see in section 3.5).

In another example, the idea according to which donor organizations would well know what is going to be useful for recipient countries does not seem to stand, given the testimonies of those who are operating on the spot and reporting little apparent relation between political statements and what they observe.

Some particular aid programs were closely analyzed as such: notably those responsible for the "Green Revolution," or for the campaign against river blindness, or still for the fight against some epidemics and some local practices detrimental to health.

In the statistical studies applying econometric methods and aiming at giving global diagnoses, it is now common to make some relevant distinctions. For instance a separate treatment is applied to humanitarian aid after natural disasters, which simultaneously cause growth to fall and aid to increase, hence generate a negative correlation between aid and growth.

In the same studies models are refined so as to better accord to some characteristics of reality. For instance, when aid is found to have on average a positive impact on growth, it may also have decreasing return, that is: Aid may be less and less beneficial on average as its volume increases, a fact which does not appear if a linear model is used.

It would be misplaced for me here to display the various categories of econometric techniques used today in order to take the full advantage of the available data. Each category has its proper field of application, because of the nature of both the data and the models suited to the investigated phenomena. The reader has just to know that econometrics became a demanding craft and to rely on those econometricians who draw the conclusions reached by them.

It so happens that in each one of the two following sections the message will be fairly clear. It will be more difficult to formulate in the long section 3.5.

3.3 Redistribution and poverty

Everything else being equal, in particular the mean purchasing power, a redistribution policy which would decrease inequality of individual incomes in a country would lessen the poverty indicator defined in section 3.1. Besley and Burgess measured the phenomenon, choosing as inequality indicator the standard deviation of the statistical distribution defined for the logarithm of individual real income.

They first noted that their inequality indicator had higher values in Latin America (around 1.0) than, say, in South Asia (around 0.6). They next evaluated how much a redistribution policy would lessen the poverty indicator in their regions of the Third World. For instance they noted that a reduction of one standard deviation in their inequality indicator in sub-Saharan Africa would cut more than half in the poverty indicator of that region.

From their computations these authors drew two conclusions. "First, finding feasible means of achieving redistribution must be a priority. ... Second, attention must be paid to the distributional impact of growth. Growth that reduces inequality will have a larger impact on poverty. This in turn leads to a focus on specific drivers of growth that can directly benefit the poor."

3.4. Short-run effects of some types of aid

In their systematic study of impacts of foreign aid on growth M. Clemens, S. Radelet and R. Bhavnani (2004) considered the aid flows into 67 countries between 1974 and 2004.

They at first divided aids into three categories: (1) Aid for disasters, emergencies and humanitarian relief efforts (including food aid); (2) Aid that might affect growth but indirectly and over a long period of time, if at all (such as aid to support democracy, the environment, health or education); (3) Aid that plausibly could stimulate growth in four years (including budget and balance of payments support, investments in infrastructure, and aid for productive sectors such as agriculture and industry).

Their focus is only on the third group, which accounts for about 53% of all aid flows.

Presenting their results concerning the effect of aid after four years, the authors state that they do not mean that even aid of the third group is always beneficial everywhere. In the wrong circumstances it can for instance help centralize the power of autocratic despots. Aid does not work equally in all countries, far from that. Some aid has been wasted and aid quality could be much improved.[5] "The big story, however, is that donors' collective, overall aid portfolio has had positive returns."

"Even at a conservatively high discount rate, at the mean, a one dollar increase in short-impact aid raises output (and income) by 1.64 dollars in present value in the typical country. ... We find that higher-than-average short-impact aid to sub-Saharan Africa raises per capita growth rates there by about half a percentage point over the growth that would have been achieved by average aid flows."

3.5. Measuring long term effects: a challenge for econometrics, but perhaps also a relevant lesson

Speaking of development is to take the stand of a long-run perspective: say 20 years rather than four. Hence, we cannot be relieved by an assertion about short-run effects, however valuable it may be. But neither can we ignore possible delusions: many factors are capable of interfering in the long run, and in principle they should be all considered simultaneously in order to reach fully convincing results. In other words, econometricians were facing a serious challenge, which did not prevent them from trying. Now, since the year 2000, signs accumulated showing that, on average, long-run effects of policies and institutions, of foreign aid in particular, might be more perverse than beneficial.

In order to appraise the difficulty we may first refer to a comment made by Easterly et al. (2004) on the article by Burnside and Dollar (2000). Their comment just amounted to show the weakness of the empirical evidence about the idea that aid would stimulate growth in countries applying good fiscal, monetary and trade policies: As a matter of fact, shifting four years ahead the period on which Burnside and Dollar had established their conclusion (no longer 1970-93 but 1974-97) was sufficient to reverse the sign of the dependence of the growth rate on the variable characterizing the conjunction of foreign aid and quality of policies.

We ask you, humbly: don't scroll away.

Hi readers, it seems you use Catholic Online a lot; that's great! It's a little awkward to ask, but we need your help. If you have already donated, we sincerely thank you. We're not salespeople, but we depend on donations averaging $14.76 and fewer than 1% of readers give. If you donate just $5.00, the price of your coffee, Catholic Online School could keep thriving. Thank you.

Help Now >

Still more disturbing are the results reached by R. Rajan and A. Subramanian (2005.b) who, after other econometricians, made a systematic investigation about the association between foreign aid and growth after ten, twenty or thirty years, and reached the conclusion that no robust relation emerged. Indeed, the dominant result was rather in the direction of aid slowing down growth. Similarly, for the category of aids identified by Clemens, Radelet and Bhavnani (2004) as having short run beneficial effect, no such effect was discerned in the long run.

Facing these econometric results two main standpoints seem to emerge, which I shall impute, for shortness, to respectively Rodrick and Rajan-Subramanian.

Since the end of the 1990s, Dani Rodrick insists on the idea that no useful conclusion can be drawn from econometric analyses of data covering a large sample of developing countries. Such analyses aim at finding a general model, complex if necessary, that would give a good account of the factors of development. In Rodrick (2006), where he speaks highly of a recent book (Work Bank-2005), this economist makes a plea for a different approach motivated by the concern for development policy advising.

Prudence and an empirical spirit would be required for finding the proper development strategy, adapted to each country at each stage of its history. Three steps should come into play: first analytical diagnostics about the most important constraints blocking economic growth; then a creative and imaginative policy design focusing on the market failures and distortions associated with the constraints; finally an appropriate set of institutional reforms. The four countries with which Rodrick illustrates such an approach gives an idea of the diversity of the means that could have to be used. Call for foreign aid is not particularly stressed.

The standpoint in Rajan-Subramanian (2005.a) is quite different, namely to aim at explaining why econometric analysis may uncover perverse effects of foreign aid and why countries should adapt their policies accordingly.

To reflect about what may be obtained from this standpoint we must first realize how serious was the econometric approach used by the authors in their paper (2005.b). The latter aimed not only at presenting important new results but also at comparing them with what was obtained earlier by other econometricians. The data cover all developing countries which received foreign aid since the last world war and for which data are available (209 countries in total).

Most results concern comparisons of performances achieved by the various countries, then analyzed with various sets of explanatory variables (between 61 and 81 countries). Comparisons were made between an initial and a terminal year (a span of 40 years between 1960 and 2000; 30 years between 1970 and 2000, 20 years between 1960 and 1980, or between 1980 and 2000).

Some results come from the analysis of panel data (with jointly various countries and various periods, each one made of five successive years; 581 observations in total). The most commented findings bear on growth achieved between the beginning and end year, as a function of the amount of aid received, of the quality of institutions, of the geographical location, of changes in terms of trade, of political stability, as well as of a number of characteristics of the condition of the country at the beginning of the period. Some results distinguish various aid categories: social, economic or food; supposed to have short- or long-run impact; multilateral or bilateral.

Which conclusions follow from this bulky investigation and some earlier made on the same issues? There are many. Given our present interest, the most important conclusions are set forth as follows: there is hardly any proof of a robust relation according to which the amount of aid would have an impact on growth; on the longest period (the 40 years between 1960 and 2000) such a relation would rather imply that aid harmed growth; there is virtually no evidence that aid works better in better institutional or geographic environments, or that certain kinds of aid work better than others. After recognizing that their results were rather disappointing, the authors write: "One explanation may simply be that the effects that even the theory would predict are too small to detect against the background noise, at least using the standard cross-sectional technique."

But they do not want to stop at that.

In their (2005.a) paper they ask two questions: "What offsets the undoubted benefits of additional resource flows to a resource-poor country? ... Why do countries with better policies or governance not seem to use aid any better?" A priori one can hardly help thinking that aid should have favorable long-run effects. The authors, however, propose two explanations.

(1) "Even though aid resources are initially additional to the budget, eventually the country becomes more lax on raising tax revenues, and more aid is necessary just to keep the country on even keel. If that aid is not forthcoming, and if the country's tax raising mechanisms have atrophied, all the short-term beneficial effects may dissipate over the long run as it creates a culture of dependency." Rajan and Subramanian report their intent to write another paper providing econometric tests of this first explanation. Hence they limit their (2005.a) paper to the second explanation.

(2) The large windfalls coming from aid and their associated spending have an insidious effect, not directly discernible on any single aid project. It is a macroeconomic effect deteriorating the country competitiveness, for instance because of an increase in the exchange rate of the country currency. That is the famous "Dutch disease" already mentioned above in section 2.2. The authors validate this thesis with two complementary empirical observations. They show that labor-intensive industries, those that should have the higher competitiveness, grow relatively slower in countries with high aid inflows. They also show that overvaluation of the real exchange rate and aid are positively correlated across industries, with the relationship becoming stronger over time.

The authors do not want, however, to be misunderstood and interpreted as dissuading donor and recipient countries from practicing foreign aid. They rather say that economists should know the existence of channels through which aid can have effects that offset possible benefits. They should pay careful attention to how much aid can be handled to begin with, to how the aid should be delivered and spent, finally to how macroeconomic management should be conducted in receiving countries. By the way, a question naturally comes to mind: why is it that we do not speak of a Norwegian disease? Norway did receive large windfalls with the extraction of energy resources from the North See.

3.6. What could be expected from microeconomics in the preparation of the agenda for reducing poverty?

The macroeconomic results, which were just surveyed, are too recent for claiming to close the debate on aid efficiency. All the more so as cynicism is already too much surrounding the thesis according to which nothing could be done for efficiently fighting against poverty in the Third World. Well then, how far did responsible economists get when facing this quite real challenge?

Let us first refer to the closing section, titled "A Realistic Vision for Foreign Aid," in Easterly (2003). Here are some quotes.

How to achieve a beneficial aggregate impact of foreign aid remains a puzzle. Aid agencies should set more modest objectives than expecting aid to "launch the takeoff into self-sustained growth." Aid agencies have misspent much effort looking for the "next big idea" that would enable aid to buy growth. ... There is no "next big idea" that will make the small amount of foreign aid the catalyst for economic growth of the world's poor nations. ... The goal is simply to benefit some poor people some of the time."

Easterly ends his paper describing how a trip to Ethiopia had given him the opportunity to visit a project led by a British NGO called Water Aid and run entirely by Ethiopians. He was glad to see that some aid dollars could reach some very needy people some of the time.

The recommendation expressed by Besley and Burgess (2003), summarizing their examination of various aspects of an agenda for reducing poverty, is not so different.

They worry about the possibility that bald assertion, intuition and ideology dominate the debate, whereas a more directly empirical approach, specific for each case, ought to prevail. They write: "It is unlikely that cross-country data will be the main vehicle for progress on" issues of liberalization, privatization or education. ... "There is need to square macro and micro facts that may sometimes be at variance with one another." "Empirical approaches based on sub national data provide the most credible base for economists to influence the debate about global poverty reduction. The evidence-based approach to policy has proven effective in industrial countries, and its expansion to the developing world is long overdue." This recommendation may be made precise in various fields.

So investment in education can be used to attack poverty both by encouraging economic growth and as a method of redistribution to the poor. But it is critical to understanding how education expansion can be achieved, with the proper incentives faced by different providers. From which appears the relevance of a large recent literature filled with evidence borrowed from micro-social and -economic observation.

Similarly, another literature, particularly developed for the Indian continent, tackles the issues of understanding the difficulty of the poor to have access to credit and of going round that difficulty in practice. There remains a gulf between the broad macro results that link credit and output, and those results that look at the micro level.

It is also critical for the developing world to find the means for an enterprising spirit to prosper. Increasing evidence shows that land rights are, for the poor farmers, an important element that may promote both equity and efficiency.

Obtaining property rights over land in urban areas can also help poor households to gain access to credit, increase labor supply and improve productivity. But unintended negative consequences can also be identified. Emphasis is then put on the role of social and business networks where contractual enforcement through formal means is imperfect.

All these considerations and others are exposed in the second half of the paper by Besley and Burgess, with important references to the literature.

--- --- ---

References

P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, ed. (2005), Handbook of Economic Growth, North-Holland, Amsterdam.
A. Atkinson (1987), "Poverty," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Macmillan Press, London.
T. Besley and R. Burgess (2003), "Halving global poverty," Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 17, No. 3, p. 3-22.

G. Burnside and D. Dollar (2000), "Aid, policies, and growth," American Economic Review, vol. 90, p. 847-68.
H. Chenery and A. Stout (1966), "Foreign assistance and economic development," American Economic Review, vol. 56, p. 679-733.
M. Clemens, S. Radelet and R. Bhavnani (2004), "Counting chickens when they hatch: the short-term effect of aid on growth," Center for Global Development, Washington.

W. Easterly (2003), "Can foreign aid buy growth?," Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 17, No. 3, p. 23-48.
W. Easterly et al. (2004), "Aid, policies, and growth: comment," American Economic Review, vol 94, No. 3, p. 774-80.
M. Friedman (1958), "Foreign economic aid," Yale Review, vol. 47, p. 501-516.

T. Kohler (1998), "Labor law and labor relations: comparative and historical perspectives," dans M. Archer and E. Malinvaud, The Future of Labour and Labour in the Future, Vatican City.
A. Lewis (1954), "Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor," Manchester School, May 22, p. 139-92.
E. Malinvaud (2004), "International justice in global economic development - Lessons from experience," Colloquium "Globalization and International Justice," Mexico City, 3-5 June 2004.

B. Nohan and C.-T. Whelan (1996), Resources, Deprivation and Poverty, Clarendon Press, Oxford.
R. Nozick (1974), Anarchy, State and Utopia, Basic Books, New York.
S. Ponthieux (2002), "La pauvreté en termes de conditions de vie," Données sociales 2002-2003, INSEE, Paris.

R. Rajan and A. Subramanian (2005.a), "What undermines aid's impact on growth?" IMF working paper 126, Washington.
R. Rajan and A. Subramanian (2005.b), "Aid and growth: what does the cross-country evidence really show?" IMF working paper 127, Washington.
J. Rawls (1971), A Theory of Justice, Harvard University Press.

P. Ricoeur (1992), Oneself as Another, The University of Chicago Press.
D. Rodrik (2005), "Growth strategies," in P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, ed. (2005).
D. Rodrik (2006), "Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? A review of World Bank (2005)," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. XLIV, n° 4, p. 973-87.

W. Rostow (1960), The Stages of Economic Growth, Cambridge University Press.
U.N. Millennium Project (2005), Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millenium Development Goals, New York.
J. Weiler (2004), "Governance without government: the normative challenge to the global legal order," in E. Malinvaud and L. Sabourin, The Governance of Globalization, Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences, Acta 9, p. 49-76.

World Bank (2005), Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform, Washington.
H. Zacher (2005), "The contribution of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences," in Democracy in Debate, Miscellanca 5, Vatican City, p. 238-309.

--- --- ---

Endnotes

[1] Contribution to the round table "International justice and aid" in the XIII plenary session of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences, 28 April 2007.

[2] On other occasions, notably in E. Malinvaud (2004), I approached fundamental philosophical issues. For that matter we should not overlook that philosophy contains important elements fostering the social doctrine of the Church. This was asserted many times by Pope John-Paul II, particularly in the long section entitled "The Church's interest in philosophy" (nn. 57-63) in the Encyclical "Fides et Ratio." He there recalled that Pope Leo XIII had devoted entirely to philosophy his Enclyclical Letter "Aeterni Patris" (1879) and that, as a result, the studies of the thought of St. Thomas and other scholastic writers had received new impetus. John Paul II also stressed "the intimate bond which ties theological work to the philosophical search for truth" (n. 63).

[3] I am referring here particularly to P. Ricoeur (1992) and to Study 9 which follows Study 7, on the inner reflection of each person on his or her aims, duties, obligations and rights, and Study 8, on the interpersonal relations inspired by solicitude and norms of reciprocity. Study 9 deals with the institutions which mediate such relations within a society, aim at justice and enforce legal obligations.

[4] See J. Weiler (2004) and H. Zacher (2005).

[5] See B. Nohan and C.-T. Whelan (1996) and for France S. Ponthieux (2003).

[6] W. Easterly, who is known as a skeptic economist about the utility of foreign aid and the (2003) article of whom deserves mentioning, went some steps in the direction of the three authors when he wrote in his conclusion: "Improving the quality of aid should come before quantity. This step is difficult but not impossible."

[Text adapted]

Contact

Catholic Online
https://www.catholic.org CA, US
Catholic Online - Publisher, 661 869-1000

Email

info@yourcatholicvoice.org

Keywords

Justice, Aid, Poverty, Solidarity, Malinvaud

More Catholic PRWire

Showing 1 - 50 of 4,716

A Recession Antidote
Randy Hain

Monaco & The Vatican: Monaco's Grace Kelly Exhibit to Rome--A Review of Monegasque-Holy See Diplomatic History
Dna. Maria St. Catherine Sharpe, t.o.s.m., T.O.SS.T.

The Why of Jesus' Death: A Pauline Perspective
Jerom Paul

A Royal Betrayal: Catholic Monaco Liberalizes Abortion
Dna. Maria St.Catherine De Grace Sharpe, t.o.s.m., T.O.SS.T.

Embrace every moment as sacred time
Mary Regina Morrell

My Dad
JoMarie Grinkiewicz

Letting go is simple wisdom with divine potential
Mary Regina Morrell

Father Lombardi's Address on Catholic Media
Catholic Online

Pope's Words to Pontifical Latin American College
Catholic Online

Prelate: Genetics Needs a Conscience
Catholic Online

State Aid for Catholic Schools: Help or Hindrance?
Catholic Online

Scorsese Planning Movie on Japanese Martyrs
Catholic Online

2 Nuns Kidnapped in Kenya Set Free
Catholic Online

Holy See-Israel Negotiation Moves Forward
Catholic Online

Franchising to Evangelize
Catholic Online

Catholics Decry Anti-Christianity in Israel
Catholic Online

Pope and Gordon Brown Meet About Development Aid
Catholic Online

Pontiff Backs Latin America's Continental Mission
Catholic Online

Cardinal Warns Against Anti-Catholic Education
Catholic Online

Full Circle
Robert Gieb

Three words to a deeper faith
Paul Sposite

Relections for Lent 2009
chris anthony

Wisdom lies beyond the surface of life
Mary Regina Morrell

World Food Program Director on Lent
Catholic Online

Moral Clarity
DAN SHEA

Pope's Lenten Message for 2009
Catholic Online

A Prayer for Monaco: Remembering the Faith Legacy of Prince Rainier III & Princess Grace and Contemplating the Moral Challenges of Prince Albert II
Dna. Maria St. Catherine Sharpe

Keeping a Lid on Permissiveness
Sally Connolly

Glimpse of Me
Sarah Reinhard

The 3 stages of life
Michele Szekely

Sex and the Married Woman
Cheryl Dickow

A Catholic Woman Returns to the Church
Cheryl Dickow

Modernity & Morality
Dan Shea

Just a Minute
Sarah Reinhard

Catholic identity ... triumphant reemergence!
Hugh McNichol

Edging God Out
Paul Sposite

Burying a St. Joseph Statue
Cheryl Dickow

George Bush Speaks on Papal Visit
Catholic Online

Sometimes moving forward means moving the canoe
Mary Regina Morrell

Action Changes Things: Teaching our Kids about Community Service
Lisa Hendey

Easter... A Way of Life
Paul Spoisite

Papal initiative...peace and harmony!
Hugh McNichol

Proclaim the mysteries of the Resurrection!
Hugh McNichol

Jerusalem Patriarch's Easter Message
Catholic Online

Good Friday Sermon of Father Cantalamessa
Catholic Online

Papal Address at the End of the Way of the Cross
Catholic Online

Cardinal Zen's Meditations for Via Crucis
Catholic Online

Interview With Vatican Aide on Jewish-Catholic Relations
Catholic Online

Pope Benedict XVI On the Easter Triduum
Catholic Online

Holy Saturday...anticipation!
Hugh McNichol

Join the Movement
When you sign up below, you don't just join an email list - you're joining an entire movement for Free world class Catholic education.

Lent logo
Saint of the Day logo

Catholic Online Logo

Copyright 2024 Catholic Online. All materials contained on this site, whether written, audible or visual are the exclusive property of Catholic Online and are protected under U.S. and International copyright laws, © Copyright 2024 Catholic Online. Any unauthorized use, without prior written consent of Catholic Online is strictly forbidden and prohibited.

Catholic Online is a Project of Your Catholic Voice Foundation, a Not-for-Profit Corporation. Your Catholic Voice Foundation has been granted a recognition of tax exemption under Section 501(c)(3) of the Internal Revenue Code. Federal Tax Identification Number: 81-0596847. Your gift is tax-deductible as allowed by law.